Title: The U.S. Congress Should Expand the TAA Program to Include Technology
Specific Purpose: Explain the technological unemployment exigency and show that income replacement through the TAA Program is the best solution. Central Idea: Algorithms are destroying American jobs for the first time in history and the US Congress should expand an existing, successful income replacement program to help workers. INTRODUCTION
The loss of jobs to technology has a very long history that until recently was good for human workers. What is Workplace Automation?
Understanding why this change has occurred is very important; the game of Go and the Uber Effect are two good examples that will help us understand ‘the why’… B. Algorithms are more than a replacement for a process because they are becoming more creative than the programmers who make them, and more efficient than the human workers they were designed to enhance.
Automation of hailing a ride by Uber and Lyft eliminated the business for 9 out of 10 New York City cabbies proving that Algorithms can be as dangerous as manufacturing jobs moving overseas, yet this is a problem that can be solved much like it has been solved before. C. The Proposal
The cost of doing nothing is huge and will cause suffering that leads to hasty action by local & national governments. D. We should understand the impact of expanding the TAA to include Tech jobs.
In conclusion, let's review and reiterate the main ideas and suggestions we reviewed today during this presentation. CONCLUSION
References
0 Comments
Following a century during which the proverbial ‘hand of government’ replaced the fickle assistance meted by monarchs and oligarchic elites, US policy makers and advocates now have a robust dataset on which to perform impact analysis of social welfare benefits, income insurance policies, and the effect of poverty protection programs on work incentives. The white paper, “Why a Universal Basic Income Is a Terrible Idea” written by Oren Cass and originally published by National Review on June 15, 2016, presents a conservative response to all Universal Basic Income (UBI) proposals which are a predominantly liberal solutions to two significant exigencies in 21st century America – poverty and technological unemployment. Cass’s white paper implies a close relationship exists between both problems, but the following analysis will be focused on the latter issue as it is the topic about which I am writing policy response speeches.
The cost of any UBI policy will be significant, diminishing the wealth of a nation’s highest earners to redirect income to meet the basic needs of people who earn the least. Supporting arguments as well as those against such a policy attempt to influence that wealthy group who controls the money today, and historically, most often controls the levers of power necessary to implement any such policy change. Whether or not the possession of money is directly related to the control of power, and the moral or ethical implications of that relationship, has been set aside by this discourse because the focus is always on one side of the exigency, or the other. Supportive arguments that favor UBI provide historical analysis, data-driven rationales, and anecdotes that attempt to engage the audience through enthymeme. Oppositional arguments, for example Cass’s white paper, tend to leverage coercive language based on institutionalized fears of change, discussions of social class, and generalized examples of potential financial challenge. In this paper, I argue that Cass’s argument is not persuasive because he constitutes an audience distrustful of facts, he ignores basic math when estimating costs, and inaccurately labels everyone who is not part of his ideology as outsiders and less worthy. Ultimately, his terrible argument against UBI disconnects from reality, disengages from the exigency it claimed as its topic, and dissolves into false claims and racist tropes that demean American citizens. Literature Review Audience as the foundation of argument enables the rhetor to choose the right word, form the most influential argument, and present evidence based on what is required according to the expectations of the immediate reader as well as the many, virtual readers who the author cannot necessarily presuppose. “A reenergized citizenry committed to carrying on the fight” (Campbell et al., 2015, p.30) aptly describes the audience for Cass’s white paper as a group of citizens, historically connected to the society – in this case Americans – who have been enthused to action by progressive arguments that threaten their grip on power and wealth. They engage in the good fight because they believe their power means that they have been right all along. Skeptically identifying the best-known speakers, thought leaders, and actors in the movement in favor of UBI is how Cass builds his credibility with his audience. In her book, Rhetorical Criticism – Exploration and Practice, Sonja K. Foss devotes a chapter to what she labels Ideological Criticism, described as “the privileging of the ideology of one group over the ideologies of other groups… that represents experience in ways that support the interests of those with more power” (Foss, 2018 p. 239). This is an obviously accurate description of the methodology Cass’s white paper deploys to argue his position. Society’s belief in his version of social norms and values must be maintained or else his argument unravels into a selfish, greedy, and isolated position that reminds me of Shelley’s poem Ozymandias written in 1817 that describes a statue of the world’s most powerful leader centuries later, now decrepit as “two vast and trunkless legs of stone stand/in the desert” (Shelley, 2002). Only the legs remain, not the body, like an argument that needs a powerful body but has only the legs to move the once powerful assertions that have been diminished by time. In addition to using norms and values to build his arguments, Cass leverages two additional techniques Foss calls Hegemonic Ideology, “position and group relations” and “ultimate authority” (Foss, 2018 p. 238). The former concept focuses on the audience as “supporters of the group members” in relation to “their enemies or opponents” while the latter asks, “what is the sanctioning agent” with the power to arbitrate what is true, or should be excluded from the argument (Foss, 2018 p. 238). The implied racism and obvious classism inherent in several of Cass’s arguments attempt to redirect factual arguments presented by eminent scholars and productive businesspeople into a narrow discussion of unsubstantiated, idealized conservative opinions of history as it relates to current affairs today. To a liberal perspective, this redirection is a necessary function of conservative discourse because the basis of their arguments is a coercive misrepresentation of historical facts necessary to support the dominant ideology. Facts matter, but not to Cass. In the following pages, I will leverage these rhetorical techniques to unravel the prejudiced, classist, elitist, and wrong-headed essay of an archconservative who is far more concerned with maintaining his white privilege than he is with discussing the merits of the arguments about progressive proposals that attempt to solve the problem of unemployment, and the related issue of poverty, through an income redistribution program named UBI. Analysis The central idea of his essay has been effectively conveyed by the title, “Why Universal Basic Income is a Terrible Idea” (Cass, 2016, pg. 1) but it reflects the core weakness of his argument, which requires a sympathetic audience and as such, does not even attempt to engage in persuasive arguments based on analysis, anecdote, or data. Cass elaborates on his central idea using a flamboyant, one-line paragraph to begin the white paper, “UBI would only entrench our misconceptions about the relationship between the individual and the state” (Cass, 2016, pg. 1) previewing his ideologically focused argument against wage replacement and social welfare benefits. He does not write for an audience of policy makers who require analysis to make decisions, but for those who are motivated by ideology and their memory of the past. Unfortunately for his argument, those memories are often incomplete and extremely limited because they include only personal perspectives. Without the more complex and nuanced objective viewpoints, his arguments can be more readily consumed by an audience who observe the discourse but do not directly participate in creating the policy response it enacts. Cass establishes his pathos by presenting a roll call of eminent think-tank writers, politicians, and economists, positioning himself as credible because he has knowledge of the issue’s current arguments. After introducing of the idea’s promoters like the chorus in a Grecian drama, “Columnists,” followed by two more groups that he names inside quote marks as “’data journalists’” and “’explainers’” he ends the list by naming the group that stands to provide the most benefit to society while also being a symptom of the unemployment problem being solved by UBI, “technologists” (Cass, 2016, pg. 1). Cass intends his use of quotes around the categorical names of his opponents to instill a skepticism of those groups in his audience. It’s his way of implying that ‘so-called’ or ‘supposed’ should precede their names because they are not part of his, and his audience’s, group. He must believe that his group is disinterested in facts but intrigued by statements that sound impressive because he uses weak data to support his position that a UBI will be cost prohibitive. The second paragraph introduces an elementary math error when estimating the cost per individual for UBI, “a monthly check of $800 or $1,000 to cover basic needs… a couple would receive $20,000 per year” (Cass, 2016, p. 1). It’s obvious that monthly checks at those amounts would be $9,600 and $12,000, not $20K, per year but the intention of his argument is not to be objective, rational, or accurate. Instead, he intends to make arguments with which his audience is already familiar because they are part of a social class and ethnic group that already fears any benefit that may be given to someone other than themselves. I agree with Foss’s point about ideological rhetoric that states a “dominant ideology controls what participants see as natural or obvious by establishing the norm” (Foss, 2018 p. 239) and the sole data-driven example in Cass’s paper attempts to establish a false fact that will be meaningful to his audience because it sounds good, without any regard for the accuracy of the basic math. Following a cost estimate that has been inflated transparently, Cass transitions to the body of his argument through a ‘They Say/I Say’ that refutes a progressive labor secretary by implying that he has presented a false obligation. “Former labor secretary Robert Reich, plugging Stern’s effort, says, ‘America has no choice.’ Actually, we do have a choice — one that goes far beyond safety-net details to reach the very heart of state and society” (Cass, 2016, p. 2). The argument against Reich is not followed by justification for an alternative opinion, but instead, the enthymeme is the conservative reverence for a secular state with heart, based on the historical values of an oppressive Caucasian majority. He reminds his audience of everlasting American norms and values, while naming his opponents as defenders of a social safety-net that is detrimental to the current moral values embodied in American society, as he sees it. As Foss explained, hegemonic ideology privileges one group above another. Cass casts his opponents as breakers of the societal covenant that he believes had been established by the prior century. For Cass, values and norms should not change. He names government as becoming a provider if UBI is enacted, implying without evidence that it will be a new role for the government. Just a paragraph earlier though, he had referenced the “safety-net programs that would no longer be necessary” but now contradictorily states that government does not provide for “individuals, families, or communities” (Cass, 2016, p. 2). Like the elementary math error that initiates his argument, contradicting himself on the same page is not a concern while he reinforces an ideological distrust of facts and logic. Cass reminds his readers about the racist and classist theories of the past, positioning the United States as a country with two sides: “the Haves” and “the poor and the black” the latter being the beneficiaries of policies “that have absolved people of responsibility for themselves and one another… and thereby eroded the foundational institutions of family and community that give shape to society” (Cass, 2016, p. 2). Cass’s narrow point of view built on racist principles created to maintain wealth and power amongst a few citizens are his replacement for concrete evidence to support his central idea. Campbell’s points to this directly when she labels an audience as a “reenergized citizenry committed to carrying on the fight” (Campbell, 2013, p.30). By grouping those in poverty with the black community, he attempts to ostracize both groups with a norm-breaking label that implies that they have not taken responsibility for themselves or their society. Like his use of skeptical quotes to label his detractors as ‘so-called’ and unworthy, Cass uses blatantly racist tropes to define his opposition to social welfare programs while attempting to establish his argument and his group as the ultimate authority. He claims that “unfulfilling” work is nonetheless imbued with meaning, which supports a conservative view of family as male-dominated, which he emphasizes by referring to the worker as a “breadwinner” who provides essentials for their family, whereas UBI would eliminate work’s “essential role as the way to earn a living, work would instead be an activity one engaged in by choice, for enjoyment, or to afford nicer things” (Cass, 2016, pg. 4). Yet work is already these things for some people at all levels of the wage scale, especially those who have earned higher wages in the past. I am an example of this type of worker, who has worked hard and sacrificed to generate enough savings through income to be able to respond to unfulfilling employment by making a life change that I believe will lead to more rewarding work. Mark Zuckerberg and other billionaires talk about how a secure financial safety net would have enabled them to invest more energy and time into their big ideas, so that the benefits to society would have been delivered sooner. “We should have a society that measures progress not by economic metrics like GDP but by how many of us have a role we find meaningful” (Zuckerberg, 2017, 18:00). Wealth as the result of innovation is a net-positive to Cass, but his ideology refuses to accept the societal changes that may accompany it, most notably when there is a cost to his audience’s wealth. Zuckerberg’s speech, most progressive discourse, and my own experience all acknowledge that work is not only essential, but also enjoyable and a choice determined by bigger factors than a need for more expensive things. Finally, Cass tries to act as the agency that sanctions what is right or wrong in the personal lives of low-income workers. He restates the Luddite Fallacy that technological progress leads to more opportunity for work. He assumes that Farm labor transitioned into Service labor. That may or not be true, but this year we have seen how providing wage support funding during the pandemic has altered the loyalty of Service workers of America to their exploitative and now potentially health-damaging employment. As reported by the Chicago Tribune, “Americans quit their jobs at a record pace for the second straight month in September” (Rugaber, 2021). Workers who are changing jobs at the highest rate in the history of America most often cite dissatisfaction and risk to health as the reason. The relatively small additional wages provided to these workers to offset job loss during the pandemic has enabled them to make a choice to select a new job with better incentives for them to work. They are not selecting the option that Cass suggests will be the outcome of UBI – i.e., not working. As he presents final arguments against providing benefits that are not tied to work programs for low-income workers, Cass uses Charles Murray’s well-known classist, misogynistic argument about the difference in intact nuclear families between 1960 – a time in history idealized by 21st Century Conservatives – and the early 2000s. His data reports that in 1960 more than 95% of children lived with two parents when mom was 40 years old, but that has declined to 60% in this century. He quotes Murray several times, reminding his audience “that it calls into question the viability of white working-class communities” (Cass, 2016, pg. 6). The difference in what he labels as intact households is more likely related the fact that stress caused by unfulfilling work is a major contributor to domestic abuse according to The American Psychological Association (APA). Guidelines for domestic abuse noted that “individuals living with LIEM [Low Income and Economic Marginalization] may suffer from increased mental health symptoms and mental health disorders; limited opportunity for engaging in healthy behaviors; and a decreased capacity to manage stressors both cognitively, mentally and socially” (Parker, 2019). Cass avoids addressing these challenges faced by LIEM households and the finding by the APA, which is indicative of a fundamental problem with the Conservative mindset that a married woman is necessarily better off. In conclusion, Cass’s white paper “Why a Universal Basic Income Is a Terrible Idea” provides an example of a Conservative American pundits who knows his audience well. The fact-lessness of his, and his audience’s, hegemonic ideology leverages weak arguments, elementary math errors, generalized and counterfactual labels for opposing voices, and overt racism to convey it’s elitist argument. According to Foss (2018), this “constitutes a kind of social control, a means of coercion, or form of domination by more powerful groups over the ideologies of those with less power” (p. 239). The values and norms of the group in power – often defined as the group with the most wealth and the most wealth to lose via redistribution policies – demand an ideology that assesses their beliefs as good and the opinions of those who disagree as contrary to society. Asserting an ultimate authority, his statistics do not need to be corroborated, nor allow any broad context that would complicate the stated opinion of his group. Despite his reliance on the principle that a citizenry can aggressively defend its ideals in the face of overwhelmingly oppositional facts, I am grateful for the ability of a citizenry to mobilize into action, to innovate for the benefit of all society and all workers, for data and anecdotes that can be validated and thus used to make better decisions about how to support workers through times of unemployment; for example, an income insurance program like UBI. References
In our modern technological society, billions of humans devote hours a day to algorithmic paradises they have created with their friends and family, communication platforms such as Facebook, Yahoo, and Reddit. Every day, humans consume messages from pundits on these platforms stating that that same beloved technology is stealing our jobs, too. The white paper, “Mounting a Response to Technological Unemployment” written by Andrew Stettner and published by The Century Foundation on April 26, 2018, is a clarion call that responds to the tension between our love of technology and its power to negatively alter the lives of hard-working people. The danger technology presents to the social well-being of society has been a growing element in Western discourse for over a century, but until the last 34 years, technological advances have tended to favor improved working conditions for humans, productivity gains, and net increases in new jobs.
In 1987, the popularization of the personal computer that fits in our pocket and performs exponentially more tasks increased the risk to our social welfare and economic well-being. The exigency is obvious to many, especially to me because I have been a 10-year participant in the building of automation that causes technological unemployment. To me, every solution to this problem seemed improbable at best, but after investing in a deep analysis of Stettner’s paper about his proposal called Technology and Trade Adjustment Assistance (TTAA) it does not seem so complicated. His paper leverages an efficient structure, legislative persona, and addresses both sides of the policy discussion by utilizing well-documented rhetorical strategies that effectively manage the many dualities in the discourse regarding income replacement to mitigate the economic risk of technological unemployment. Campbell’s seven elements of descriptive analysis can be found in this white paper in support of the argument that some form of income replacement is a good solution to the problem created by technological unemployment. I will focus primarily on Structure, secondarily on Persona, as well as two frequently used rhetorical techniques: analogy and negating. In addition, I will analyze how the author effectively deploys the “They Say / I Say” argument to address criticisms of his proposal quickly, so that he can devote most of his attention to setting the stage and elaborating the solution. Structure, how “materials are organized to gain attention, develop a case, and provide emphasis” (Campbell et al., 2015, p. 28), is the primary focus of my analysis because Stettner’s document provides a useful template for the final policy speech that I will present at the end of this class. The exigency that is my focus is familiar to our policy-making audiences, without being well-known, and as such requires a greater investment in staging context, current research, and approaches attempted, before progressing to any presentation of a solution proposal. I believe that one of this document’s greatest strengths is how it resolves the complexity inherent in this exigency by allocating space (text) very effectively to the constituent objects of the argument. Stettner’s white paper was produced to represent the position of the well-respected think-tank that supported it’s publication. Written for a virtual audience of policy makers who will read it, he makes assumptions about the priorities and objections of his audience and addresses them with a persona that implies he is an experienced legislator even though he is not. Frequently, the text presumes objections and foresees legislative challenges, directly addressing them using the two rhetorical techniques that I will analyze in detail. Analogy and negation have a natural relationship because they are both dichotomous rhetoric techniques best suited to build similarities and eliminate the complexity created by multiple, opposing entities. The entities in my exigency frequently conflict because they are poorly understood, and because they are relatively new observations that lack clear direction for policy proposals. In his white paper, Stettner minimizes complexity to undercut our anxiety about the competing options to resolve the exigency while also insisting that it is real and resolvable. Any worthy presentation – written or spoken to a live audience – must begin immediately and effectively, and this white paper does it well. The title, “Mounting a Response to Technological Unemployment” is a clear call to action that immediately presents the central idea that will be first contextualized by scoping the problem through evidence, then related to existing inertia observed in parallel policies, and finally elaborated into a more detailed solution that targets the stated problem. The paper is structured simply: introduction, problem context with historical and current perspectives, alternative or parallel solutions, proposed solution with answers to rebuttals, and conclusion. I am extremely impressed that his introduction is a mere 425 words and his conclusion even less, 131 words from a total 15,000 words; only 3.7% of text surround the body of his argument. Because I believe that the structure of this paper provides a template for my policy speech, it is important to further this analysis. After the introduction, the next 4,200 words (28%) provide the context and history, as well as current research about the problem. Stettner’s effort to stage the context and history that favor his solution reference several of the same citations that I used in my Problem Speech, although I found that his argument about the impact of ATMs on the employment of bank tellers did not include the additional demographic information that I had identified using the US Labor Statistics information about the relevant time-period. He stated, “But in fact, they’ve allowed banks to increase the number of branches, each with fewer tellers focused more on customer service” (Stettner, 2018, p. 3) whereas my argument dug deeper. Though our arguments were initiated by the same article in the Journal of Economic Perspectives written by David H. Autor in 2015 my speech included the following, per the outline, “Seeing that example from Autor, I found the overall US employment statistics for the same period… US had 91M workers in 1980 and 139M workers in 2010, a 55% increase, compared to the 10% increase in bank tellers after ATMs… Negative on jobs at both the micro-level of bank [tellers] and across the industry at a macro-level” [italics added for emphasis] (Frazier, 2021, p. 6). As I learned first-hand, an important aspect of the policy discussion about technological unemployment is the Luddite Fallacy. I presented it in my speech as the counterargument to the position that robots will take away our jobs. It may have been an oversight, but in my opinion, Stettner included the incomplete data about the ATM example to include a reference to the Luddite Fallacy counterargument that rounds out the historical context for technological unemployment, even though it detracts from his thesis. After the context and history of the exigency has been presented, he transitions to the current research: a thorough index of alternative solutions to employment problems and a deep dive into a program implemented in the 1960s to protect workers from job losses created by employment migration out of the United States caused by the progressive trade policies at that time. Of the previously noted 4,200 words prior to the solution proposal, his description of current research utilizes 2,900 words (nearly 20% of the entire document). This is a long section, which he acknowledges when he writes that his “paper goes into depth about the possibility and merits of expanding TAA, providing more details to an idea that has been briefly mentioned in the literature but not fleshed out” avoiding the challenges of building something new, deftly titling his solution section, “Expanding TAA to Include Technology: The Extra T in TAA” (Stettner, 2018, p. 21). He suggests that the Trade Adjustment Assistance program legislated in 1962 can be modified to include compensation to workers for technology-related job losses in addition to the existing benefits for job losses due to trade migration. He positions this program as the best option among the many alternatives listed in his index of solutions partly because he is just fleshing out an idea that was already approved by the United States Congress. This understated language belies Stettner’s persona throughout his policy argument which aligns to the publisher’s stated mission to be a “progressive, independent think tank that conducts research, develops solutions, and drives policy change to make people’s lives better” (The Century Foundation, About Us, 2021) by focusing the audience of policy makers on those humans about which they may have minimal direct personal knowledge, the middle class and the low-skilled labor in the United States. The last paragraph of his introduction begins with an assumption that reflects the inertia his argument is trying to leverage using a legislative voice, “the growing consensus on the types of tasks that are vulnerable to displacement” that finishes with a list of policy jargon such as “displacement… trade-related job losses… adjustment assistance… elements of a policy response to this risk… pilot program… underlying TAA program” (Stettner, 2018, p. 1). I hear him signaling to his audience his credibility as a policy thought leader who writes like a legislative insider. Aside from this strong presence at the beginning of this argument, though, he steps back to allow the context, history, and current research to tell the story, and the data to provide the evidence that supports the central idea captured in the title of his white paper. To mount a response to technological unemployment, Stettner builds a linguistic analogy between the existing TAA program and his solution that uses semantic likeness as a technique to generate confidence in his proposal. Because this “analogy is a fresh comparison that strikes the audience as highly apt, it has considerable persuasive force” (Campbell et al., 2015, p. 99). By investing almost 1,700 words (11%) in a detailed description of the benefits, successes, and improvement opportunities related to the TAA program, I see a good example of how to utilize Campbell’s opinion of analogy, “[a]s a rule, a figurative analogy is more powerful when it is more comprehensive; that is, when there are many points of similarity” (Campbell et al., 2015, p. 99). Stettner has been comprehensive by including extensive historical and contextual perspective, as well as current research in the form of the existing TAA program, which enables him to use analogy to bridge to his solution proposal by simply adding an “Extra T in TAA” (Stettner, 2018, p. 21). After his effort to build many strong connections between the existing program and his proposed response to the problem of technological unemployment, Stettner dedicates the next 25% of his text to the solution. To reduce the apparent complexity of his solution proposal and in contrast to the detailed lists of policy requirements, goals, and mitigations, he refers to the “TTAA” program that is his proposed solution as “[t]his straightforward expansion would make the same mix of services available to both trade- or technology-certified workers” (Stettner, 2018, p. 25). This is a great example of negating as described in our textbook, “negation underlies all comparisons and contrasts, including those involved in literal and figurative analogies… but comparisons are also involved in definitions” (Campbell et al., 2015, p. 170) in this case trying to reset any anxiety that may have developed in his audience as they progressed through his solution proposal. Almost immediately after using “straightforward” he again uses negation “to characterize a person or thing” (Campbell et al., 2015, p. 188) by describing the benefits provided by the existing program he wants to mimic as a “current menu of standard options” (Stettner, 2018, p. 25) as if the audience were seated at a restaurant reviewing a list of entrees from which to choose their meal. This familiar language understates the complexity of his argument, effectively leveraging the analogy to simplify the policy argument. The solution can be further bisected into a closing rebuttal to what he believes are the two primary ambiguities that might stymie his plan. As a paper directed to policy makers, he addresses their first concern like a legislator, “many forms of artificial intelligence and automation, like autonomous vehicles, may need Congressional or regulatory permission to expand. These may provide political opportunities for enacting a program like TTAA in exchange for government approval of the technology” (Stettner, 2018, p. 26). Any concerns about how to qualify industries and workers for the program, he calls “a seemingly minor but important detail… unemployment records typically track the workers industry” (Stettner, 2018, p. 26) unifying both ends of the classification problem using those final two words cited and addressing the challenged relationship between workers and industry as minor but solvable through the well-known unemployment assistance program. I found a comparable semantic problem examined in a paper published by the MIT Technology Review that described Andrew Yang’s challenge with presenting Universal Basic Income to Americans as resolved when “he workshopped multiple options before landing on ‘freedom dividend’” qualified by the author’s opinion, “After all, capitalism has become synonymous with the American dream, and what’s more capitalistic than a dividend? And freedom ... well, that part speaks for itself” (Guo, 2021). Stettner’s and Yang’s figurative analogies, workers industry and freedom dividend, characterize the effect of the programs to create a definition of the solution and the impact it will have on people. I see this as a great example of Campbell’s definition of negation. Finally, to address several negative findings related to the existing TAA program, Stettner uses “They say/I say” as swift rebuttal, removing counterarguments quickly. For example, “This is not simply a failing of the program or its model, but rather reflects the fact that TAA recipients are laid off in communities with few good jobs,” (Stettner, 2018, p. 18) to further deepen our concern about the unemployment problems that relate to his argument. He goes further when he adds, “In short, it’s time for a closer look at the results of TAA, and to put to bed the idea that it’s an ‘ineffective’ program” (Stettner, 2018, p. 18). Like his use of “menu” cited earlier, and the use of “workers industry” and “freedom dividend” as well, phrasing opposition’s argument as being ready for bedtime diminishes their power. These semantic analogies link the concepts being discussed to familiar, non-threatening, aspects of daily life. He has heard the counterarguments to his proposal, which focus on perceived challenges to the existing TAA program’s success rate, and he quickly responds by adding that the challenges were already, and continued to be, in the affected communities. A great strength of this paper is that is does not try to reinvent the wheel to solve a problem that is roughly 34 years old. Often, new problems lead one to think deeply about new solutions. Instead, this argument eloquently relates the technological unemployment problem to an issue that has existed for almost twice as long, trade-related unemployment. This approach enables a frequent use of analogy, instead of mind-numbing explanations of complicated, new solutions, to support his argument and to focus on his central idea, mounting a response to technological unemployment as proclaimed by the title of his paper. There are so many risks with engaging the problem of technological unemployment in a way that will effectively mitigate it with an equitable solution that does not interfere with the natural capitalistic imperative to create new gadgets, bots, and algorithms that simplify our life while enriching the wealth of creators. As I have discussed above, this paper published by The Century Foundation avoids those risks by investing semantic resources in an effectively designed structure that efficiently allocates the most text where it is most needed, exposing and resolving the dualities inherent in this exigency with effective use of implicitly dichotomous rhetorical techniques, while quickly addressing disagreements and presumed challenges with “They Say / I Say” arguments. The solution to this problem has always seemed complex to me, as it does to most people, but maybe not so much anymore. The author’s Technology and Trade Adjustment Assistance (TTAA) program does not exist yet, but I can see it clearly now. That is the strength of analogy. Andrew Stettner’s proposed program addresses the risk to social cohesion created by rapid advances in technology without limiting the opportunities for wealth and convenience that are required by our capitalistic, freedom-loving American society. References
|
AuthorStudent of Education, English, and Learning Technology at UMN. Archives
May 2022
Categories
All
|